Social norms and licence choice: What motivates free software developers to choose between copyleft and permissive licences?

facebooktwittergoogle_plusredditlinkedinmail

Free software licences can be divided into two broad categories: copyleft licences (like the GPL), which require derivatives of the software to be licensed under the same terms; and permissive licences (like the MIT/X11 licence), which allow the software to be reused in any project, even closed-source projects. There are variations, of course – the LGPL, for example, is a ‘weak copyleft’, allowing licensed works to be used in closed-source works, but requiring improvements to the work itself to be released under a copyleft licence.

The licences express a difference in opinion about free-riding and user rights. The copyleft licences, championed by Stallman and the Free Software Foundation, explicitly focus on the importance of preserving the freedoms of downstream users, who may lose the ability to use, examine, share, and improve the software. In this way, the copyleft requirement reflects an instrumental goal to increase the free software commons and safeguard the freedom of future users. Implicitly, however, the licences also reflect a particular view about fairness: a sense that it is wrongful for others to take from the commons without sharing in turn. The permissive licences, on the other hand, do not treat free-riding as harmful; instead, they reflect a particular view which seeks to maximise the utility of software by refusing to restrict free-riders from appropriating its benefits.

A 2008 study by Sen, Subramaniam, and Nelson1 found that intrinsic motivations (beliefs about redistribution rights or social benefits of FLOSS) have a stronger effect on licence choice than extrinsic motivations (expection of reputation or economic gain). Perhaps not surprisingly, the study also showed that developers who agreed with the statement that “OSS licenses should give everyone the freedom to distribute derivative software under any license”, were “approximately 72 percent less likely to choose a Strong-Copyleft over a Non-Copyleft license.” Conversely, developers who saw FOSS development as one of their “social responsibilities”, “duty towards society”, or “social obligation” were “approximately 52 percent more likely to choose Strong-Copyleft over Non-Copyleft” licences. This suggests that a developer’s view about the morality of software licensing is a strong, but not necessarily decisive, factor in licence choice.

It seems intuitive that views about user rights and social responsibilities inform licence choice. It is probably more important to ask where these views come from, and how they propagate. The choice of licence appears likely to be substantially determined by social norms. A recent study by Singh and Phelps2 suggests that “the most important factor determining a new project’s license choice is the type of license chosen by existing projects that are socially closer to it in its inter-project social network.” Less experienced managers of free software projects, in particular, are strongly susceptible to influence from others, and the licences chosen by similar projects has a strong influence on licence choice.

The choice between copyleft and permissive free software licences illustrates two fascinating points:

  1. Whether developers feel harmed by free-riding may be largely a result of the norms of their social network. This could have significant ramifications, since it effects their willingness to voluntarily participate in projects in the face of free riding.

  2. The copyleft licences are a neat hack of traditional copyright practices that enable developers to set boundary conditions that create a commons that is neither fully closed nor fully open. The GPL is non-discriminatory – it allows any potential user to join the commons, but imposes certain rules of participation. By doing so, it articulates a set of boundary conditions that are important to the community, but stops well short of total exclusivity.

The interesting question for me is how this might play out in other fields. Many Kickstarter projects, for example, are almost fully funded by a large crowd of backers and only made available to those backers and future purchasers. These commons are closed; free-riders are excluded from access. What then, might motivate the choice of some producers to release their content under an open licence once it has been funded? Experiments like commonly.cc and unglue.it (discussed here and here before) show that there is movement in some of these attitudes, and suggest the possibility that pro-sharing norms might spread to influence other producers.

facebooktwittergoogle_plusredditlinkedinmail
  1. Sen, R., Subramaniam, C., & Nelson, M. L. (2008). Determinants of the Choice of Open Source Software License Journal of Management Information Systems, 25(3), 207–239. []
  2. Singh, P. V., & Phelps, C. (2012). Networks, Social Influence, and the Choice Among Competing Innovations: Insights from Open Source Software Licenses. Information Systems Research. doi:10.1287/isre.1120.0449 []
Comments are closed.